Sökalternativ
Hem Media Förklaringar Forskning och publikationer Statistik Penningpolitik €uron Betalningar och marknader Karriär och jobb
Förslag
Sortera efter
Nikola Bokan
Pascal Jacquinot
Magdalena Lalik
Georg Müller
Romanos Priftis
Lead Economist · Economics, Forecasting and Policy Modelling
Rodolfo Rigato
Inte tillgängligt på svenska

Macroeconomic impacts of higher defence spending: a model-based assessment

Prepared by Nikola Bokan, Pascal Jacquinot, Magdalena Lalik, Georg Müller, Romanos Priftis and Rodolfo Rigato

Published as part of the ECB Economic Bulletin, Issue 6/2025.

1 Introduction

This article uses a suite of models to analyse the macroeconomic impact of higher government defence spending. In June 2025 members of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) committed to increase core defence and other related spending by a volume unprecedented in recent history. In light of this pledge, we revisit the size of fiscal multipliers and their determinants across a range of ECB macroeconomic models. This article complements previous ECB analyses by highlighting the role of model differences in the quantification of economic effects of public spending.[1]

Simulations are conducted around an increase in government consumption from 2% of GDP in 2024 to 3% of GDP by 2028 that illustrates a stylised expansion of defence-related purchases (Chart 1).[2] The increase begins in 2025, reaches its peak by early 2028 and remains at this higher level for ten years, after which it gradually returns to its original level.

Using alternative model settings makes it possible to explore the determinants of fiscal multipliers and inflation estimates. This article looks at the effects of public spending increases on macroeconomic variables under a benchmark setting before studying the transmission under alternative specifications. It shows (i) the importance of private sector expectations about future financial market developments and deficit financing; (ii) the distributional aspects of increased government spending; and (iii) the extent of intra-euro area spillovers, which in turn vary depending on the instrument used or the origin of imports. The model-based assessment is complemented by Box 1, which puts the model-based results into perspective by providing an overview of fiscal multipliers in the relevant empirical literature on defence spending.

Chart 1

Counterfactual path of the increase in government defence spending

(percentage of GDP)

Source: Authors’ assumptions.

2 Benchmarking fiscal multipliers across models

To cover a wide range of transmission channels, the analysis uses both semi-structural and dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models developed at the ECB. The semi-structural models employed include core projection models, namely the ECB-MC model (Angelini et al., forthcoming) and its euro area counterpart, ECB-BASE (Angelini et al., 2019 and Bańkowski, 2023). We also use a version of the latter that incorporates forward-looking expectations: ECB-REBASE (Adjemian et al., 2024). In addition, we employ two DSGE models. The first is an extended version of the ECB’s NAWM-E model (Coenen et al., 2024), which incorporates a global and regionally disaggregated structure.[3] The second, which is a newly developed model with household heterogeneity – a so-called Heterogeneous-Agent New Keynesian model, or HANK model (see Kase and Rigato, 2025) – allows us to capture distributional effects more explicitly. We introduce the same government purchase shock into all models and harmonise the simulation modalities to the extent possible. Importantly, monetary policy is assumed to be active across all simulations.[4]

The average output multiplier of government spending across models is 0.93 over a two-year horizon, although there is substantial heterogeneity. Chart 2 shows the GDP multiplier and the impact on GDP growth and HICP (Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices) inflation for each model. The multipliers shown here are within the range of those in the empirical literature (Box 1). Overall, semi-structural models display higher multipliers than DSGE models. This mostly owes to (i) the absence of expectation channels regarding the financing of the resulting deficit through taxation in the benchmark setting, and (ii) the smaller effects of interest rates on consumption decisions. By contrast, in DSGE models, the additional spending is necessarily financed with a mix of debt and taxes, which leads to stronger crowding-out owing to the effects of taxation on private sector expectations of future disposable income. Semi-structural models also tend to display a weaker role for monetary policy stabilisation. On the contrary, DSGE models feature strong inter-temporal reallocation via the real interest rate channel. The nominal-side transmission also differs depending on the properties of the model, with the HANK model displaying stronger effects on HICP inflation, mostly because inflation is more sensitive to economic cost pressures in the parameterisation used. The global and regional extension of NAWM-E shows weaker effects, and semi-structural forecast models fall somewhere in between. Given the numerous model-specific characteristics that affect the size of the fiscal multiplier, the following sections explore how the transmission mechanism of government spending can vary when relevant channels are altered.

Chart 2

Impact of an increase in government consumption across models

a) GDP multiplier

(relative change in GDP per unit change in government spending)


b) GDP growth

(percentage point deviation from baseline)


c) HICP inflation

(percentage point deviation from baseline)

Source: ECB staff calculations.
Notes: The government consumption shock is calibrated as a linear increase of 1% of GDP over three years; the level then remains constant over the medium term (Chart 1). The GDP multiplier at horizon k is defined as t=1kβtYt-Yt=1kβtGt-G where Yt and Gt refer to real GDP and government spending respectively, letters without subscripts refer to steady state or baseline values and β is a discount factor. The benchmark simulation modalities incorporate active monetary policy. All the models except for the extended NAWM-E operate without open-economy feedback and without exchange rate reactions. The semi-structural models assume full deficit financing of the fiscal spending, as their benchmark setting does not feature a tax rule (“fixed tax rate”). The additional expenditure is then financed with public debt issuance.

3 The role of expectations: anticipating financial market responses and future disposable income

Private sector expectations can greatly influence the macroeconomic effects of increased government spending. To understand this interaction, we compare the predictions of two models with different assumptions regarding the expectations formations mechanism. The first model (ECB-BASE) assumes backward-looking expectations. Generally speaking, this implies that economic agents form their expectations on the basis of historical regularities and past information only. By contrast, the second model (ECB-REBASE) assumes that agents are forward-looking and incorporate news about future shocks and economic developments into their current decisions. This expectation formation mechanism is called model-consistent expectations.

Stronger forward-looking behaviour leads to an earlier and faster increase in financing rates, with an adverse impact on investment, but may stimulate consumption via households’ expectations of higher future income.[5] Chart 3 compares the macroeconomic response with backward-looking (blue lines) and forward-looking (yellow lines) expectations with unchanged tax rates. Under backward-looking expectations, there is consumption and investment crowding-in as the economy gradually becomes aware of the demand and income impulse, with financial conditions tightening only gradually. Under the forward-looking setting, expectations of future policy rate hikes are reflected in long-term interest rates sooner, and the resulting worsening of borrowing conditions adversely affects investment dynamics over the shorter horizon. Generally, consumption decisions are also affected by tighter borrowing conditions, albeit to a much lesser extent than investment decisions. Instead, consumption increases on account of higher expected income.[6] The prospects of higher income in the future are anticipated in the forward-looking model, which leads to stronger consumption dynamics. In both the BASE and the REBASE model specifications, private consumption and investment are estimated to be crowded out over the longer run as the effects of higher production and incomes start to fade and the financial market tightening causes the economy to contract. Anticipation of the spending pattern in the forward-looking model also leads to mild frontloading in price and wage setting dynamics and, in turn, to a somewhat faster increase in HICP inflation.

The output multiplier is considerably lower if the public deficit is expected to be financed through an increase in labour taxes. The red and green lines in Chart 3 show specifications where the budget deficit is financed via an increase in taxes on labour income, which introduces an anticipation of future tax hikes at the onset of the increase in military spending. Two financing assumptions for the deficit are shown: a partial tax-financing scheme that still leads to a mild increase in public debt and an illustrative extreme case of full financing via higher taxes. In the forward-looking model, households internalise the repercussions for their future disposable income streams and strongly curtail their current consumption. Despite lower price pressures being somewhat beneficial for investment owing to rather limited changes to financial indicators, the bulk of the output multiplier is determined by consumption dynamics. As a result, output multipliers are dampened considerably.

Chart 3

The role of expectations through the lens of ECB-(RE)BASE

(x-axis: quarters; y-axis: deviation from the balanced growth path/baseline)

Source: ECB staff calculations using the BASE and REBASE models.
Notes: The spending increase is interpreted as a government consumption (purchases) shock. The simulations are run with active monetary policy and an active tax rate response wherever indicated. The exchange rate, the term premium and financing spreads are not allowed to react to the shock. “VAR expectations” refers to expectations formed through a vector autoregression that is a simplified model of the full model economy that is based on historical regularities and fed by current and past information only. “Full MCE” refers to model-consistent expectations assumed across all sectors of the model economy. Year-on-year HICP inflation is expressed as percentage point deviations from its baseline growth rate. Interest rates are expressed as percentage point deviations of the annualised rate from its baseline rate. The annualised government debt ratio (relative to GDP) is expressed as percentage point deviations from its baseline ratio. All other variables are shown as percentage deviations from the baseline level.

4 Distributional consequences and the role of marginal propensities to consume

This section explores the distributional aspects of the fiscal stimulus. It employs the HANK model, which features heterogenous households with large and dispersed marginal propensities to consume (MPCs). As is typical in this class of model, and in line with empirical evidence, households at the bottom of the income distribution have higher MPCs than those at the top. Like in the other models, an increase in government spending is associated with an increase in real GDP, despite a crowding-out effect on private consumption. The blue lines on Chart 4 show the implications of the fiscal shock under a benchmark specification of the HANK model. Private consumption and investment are significantly crowded out owing to both higher interest rates and higher labour taxes.

The effects of fiscal policy are amplified when the additional government spending is targeted towards sectors that employ low-income households. The red lines on Chart 4 show the results under this alternative specification. Since MPCs are negatively correlated with income, in this case the additional spending generates an additional stimulus to private consumption. In contrast to the benchmark specification, there is initially a slight crowding-in effect on private consumption. Consequently, HICP inflation is higher than in the benchmark, as are short-term interest rates. This generates a larger crowding-out of private investment, but the fiscal multiplier remains higher than in the benchmark specification.

Chart 4

The role of non-Ricardian behaviour and MPC heterogeneity

(x-axis: quarters; y-axis: deviations from steady state)

Source: ECB staff calculations using the HANK model.
Notes: GDP, private consumption and private investment are shown as percentage deviations from the steady state. HICP inflation and the short-term interest rate are in percentage points, while government debt is expressed as a percentage of steady state output.

The effects of additional military spending on consumption are positive at the bottom of the wealth distribution and negative at the top. Chart 5 shows the distributional consequences of the increase in government spending under the benchmark specification of the HANK model. Each line corresponds to a different group of households in terms of wealth holdings. There is a clear pattern: households at the bottom of the wealth distribution increase consumption, whereas consumption at the middle and top is crowded out. Since MPCs are larger at the bottom, the increase in labour demand and wages coming from the additional government spending tends to stimulate consumption for those households. At the middle and top of the wealth distribution, higher interest rates and expectations of higher future taxes play a larger role, leading to the observed crowding-out.

Chart 5

Effects of additional government spending across the wealth distribution

(x-axis: quarters; y-axis: percentage deviation of consumption from steady state)

Source: ECB staff calculations using the HANK model.
Note: The lines show the average consumption of different household groups sorted by wealth and expressed as percentage deviations from steady state values.

5 Backloaded versus frontloaded spending

This section explores how fiscal multipliers vary when additional government spending is announced in advance of its implementation. This is particularly relevant in the case of the current defence-related commitments, as these have been publicly announced and discussed well in advance of the actual spending, which materialises over a longer period. In contrast to social transfers that are related to automatic stabilisers, discretionary defence spending measures are backloaded and gradual.

Backloaded spending leads to substantially lower effects on real GDP. Chart 6 shows fiscal multipliers for pre-announced fiscal shocks in the REBASE and HANK models. Each point on the curve corresponds to the fiscal multiplier of a one-time increase in government consumption as a function of the number of quarters by which its announcement precedes its implementation. Notably, the spending increase is identical – only the implementation date changes. When agents are forward-looking, the fiscal multipliers decrease as the time between announcement and implementation increases. This is because the prospect of increases in taxes and interest rates owing to future increases in government expenditure leads to an immediate crowding-out of private spending.

Chart 6

Dynamic multipliers of pre-announced shocks

(x-axis: number of quarters between spending announcement and implementation; y-axis: long-run present-value multiplier)

Source: ECB staff calculations using REBASE and HANK models.
Notes: Each point corresponds to the long-run present-value multiplier for a spending increase implemented at different points in time. The long-run present-value multiplier is the cumulative multiplier over the entire horizon. For REBASE, the specification with a tax rule is shown. “Full MCE” refers to model-consistent expectations assumed across all sectors of the model economy.

6 Cross-country spillovers

This section looks at the cross-country spillovers of government spending and how these can vary depending on key features of the spending. We first benchmark the effects through the lens of the ECB-MC model. Given the workhorse nature of this model, important parameters, such as the import content of government spending, are set to historical averages. We then consider alternative scenarios using the global and regional extension of NAWM-E to provide a more qualitative illustration from alternative sensitivity exercises.

Both government consumption and government investment generate positive domestic real effects, but the magnitude of spillovers across euro area countries varies depending on the import content of the instrument (Chart 7). Government consumption is assumed to rely mostly on domestic production, with an import share of only around 10%. By contrast, government investment has a much higher import share of around 30%.[7] As a result, in the short to medium run government consumption causes a stronger increase in domestic output than government investment, while spillover effects on other countries remain small – and even turn negative after three years – as the rise in policy rates outweighs the positive trade effects over the longer term. Conversely, government investment generates positive spillovers throughout the horizon, as it stimulates private investment and partially offsets the dampening effect of higher interest rates.

Chart 7

Domestic and spillover effects of government spending during the third year after the shock

a) Real GDP

(percentage deviation from baseline levels)


b) HICP inflation

(percentage deviation from baseline levels)

Source: ECB-MC simulations.
Notes: The x-axis shows the impact on the country where the shock occurs and the y-axis shows the spillover on the remaining big five economies (Germany, Spain, France, Italy and the Netherlands). For example, for government consumption in panel a), the dark blue dot shows that an increase in government consumption in France increases French real GDP by 1.2% and leads to a negative spillover of -0.04% on the rest of the big five economies.

On the nominal side, government consumption and investment raise domestic inflation and generate inflationary spillovers across countries but do so in different ways. Government consumption is substantially more inflationary, as it directly increases demand without boosting productive capacity. By contrast, government investment raises inflation in the short term but, by strengthening trend productivity, also helps to ease price pressures over the medium term.

Spillovers operate mainly through the trade channel and less so through interest rates, with the net effect on the euro area appearing limited in magnitude. Chart 8 disentangles the transmission channels using the global extension of the NAWM-E model and shows that higher German public spending raises domestic demand, which initially boosts output. However, under the benchmark calibration, higher government demand crowds out private demand over time.[8] This is because stronger public demand puts upward pressure on prices and wages, raising the cost of borrowing and reducing households’ and firms’ real disposable income and profitability.[9] At the same time, the increased demand for imports improves the trade balance of Germany’s euro area partners, supporting their exports and output. However, as prices rise in Germany, the real exchange rate appreciates, which dampens German export competitiveness and increases imports further. This real appreciation partly offsets the boost to net exports for the rest of the euro area. For the euro area, the higher aggregate demand and price pressures push up inflation. In response, the central bank raises the policy rate negligibly, suggesting that the impact of this tightening on private consumption and investment – via the traditional interest rate channel – is likely to be limited.

Chart 8

Macroeconomic effects of increased defence expenditure in Germany according to the extended version of NAWM-E

(x-axis: quarters; y-axis: deviations from steady state)

Source: Simulations using the global and regional extension of the NAWM-E model.
Notes: The simulation assumes a temporary increase in German government consumption spending by 1% for two years starting from period 0. The additional spending is then reduced every quarter by a factor of 0.9. Responses are expressed as percentage deviations from the baseline, except for inflation, trade balance and the short-term interest rate, which are expressed as percentage point deviations.

A higher share of imported goods and services leads to stronger spillovers to the rest of the euro area, but the overall effects on the euro area remain similar. For example, if Germany ramps up defence purchases involving foreign equipment or invests in infrastructure projects requiring imported machinery, a larger share of the increased demand leaks abroad, directly boosting exports and production in Germany’s trading partners (Chart 9, yellow lines).[10] As a result, the trade channel becomes stronger, and spillovers to the rest of the euro area grow larger. However, the overall effects on euro area output are similar to the scenario with spending that is predominantly domestically sourced, as higher production in the rest of the euro area is offset by import leakage in Germany and a general appreciation of the euro area real exchange rate.

Chart 9

The role of the import content of government consumption

(x-axis: quarters; y-axis: deviations from steady state)

Source: Simulations using the global and regional extension of the NAWM-E model.
Notes: The simulation assumes a temporary increase in German government consumption spending by 1% for two years starting from period 0, after which there is a gradual unwinding. Responses are expressed as percentage deviations from the baseline, except for inflation, trade balance, and the short-term interest rate, which are expressed as percentage point deviations. Higher import content assumes that the import content of government consumption is doubled from 2% to 4%.

Box 1
Fiscal multipliers of defence spending: a short review of the empirical literature

Prepared by Cristina Checherita-Westphal and Laust Ladegård Særkjær

Although the evidence is mixed across the empirical literature, it suggests that military spending can have positive short-term demand effects which then tend to decrease over time. This broadly confirms the model-based effects of the general government spending increase considered in this article, although results are more dispersed across samples and various state dependencies (Chart A). The size of the defence spending multiplier differs significantly across studies, with the shorter-run effects in most cases below or close to 1 – broadly in line with the suite of model results presented above – although values close to 1.5 are found in several studies. Very few studies directly analyse the impact of higher defence spending on private consumption.[11] Ilzetzki (2025), one of the most recent literature reviews, concludes that there is a consensus that GDP does increase following higher defence spending, but the degree of this expansion and the potential crowding-out of the private sector are debated. He also points out that two meta-analyses on the topic disagree on the conclusions. Alptekin and Levine (2012), a meta-study of 169 estimates of the military spending multiplier, suggests that military spending has positive, but small, growth effects. Conversely, the updated sample of F. Yesilyurt and M. E. Yesilyurt (2019) shows no relationship. Finally, in their meta-analysis of fiscal multipliers, Gechert and Rannenberg (2018) find that military spending tends to have lower average multipliers than general government spending,[12] a finding corroborated by a recent study analysing the output effects of defence spending in the central and eastern European members of NATO’s eastern flank (Olejnik, 2023).

There is also considerable heterogeneity in the output effects of various components of military expenditure. The growth effects of military research and development (R&D) spending are found to be considerably higher than those of other components and to exceed unity, with evidence of crowding-in of private R&D.[13] For the other spending categories, and particularly over the medium to long run, higher defence expenditure is usually found to crowd out resources available for productive purposes. Expenditure on wages or military personnel (not directly covered in the model simulation results above) is found to have lower or (in the longer run) even negative growth effects, as such spending may impede productivity in the remaining civilian sectors of the economy (see Chart A and additional findings in Becker and Dunne, 2023).

Chart A

Fiscal multipliers of military spending in more recent studies

(increase in GDP from a one unit increase in defence spending, unless otherwise specified)

Sources: Publications indicated in the chart.
Notes: The dot represents the (main) estimate of the cumulative defence spending multiplier and the bands indicate one standard deviation when available or readily calculated. When multiple results were available, the selection was made based on the original author’s preferred specification to ensure a relevant comparison to the other studies, and for a one and four-year horizon (centre of the shorter and medium to long-term horizons respectively).

In general, the multipliers measure an increase in GDP from a one unit (e.g. USD 1 or €1) increase in defence spending. For the studies marked with (*), the multiplier measures the percentage point increase in the GDP growth rate following a one percentage point increase in the defence-spending-to-lagged GDP ratio. For the studies marked with (†), the multiplier measures the percentage point increase in GDP relative to trend from a one per cent increase in defence spending relative to trend GDP.
Other studies have used military spending (news) as an instrument for more general government spending. For the United States, Ramey and Zubairy (2018) find the fiscal multiplier to be below one regardless of the slack in the economy. Using a large panel of countries, Sheremirov and Spirovska (2022) find that the average multiplier is below unity, with the largest impact at short horizons, but this is subject to heterogeneity along multiple dimensions. Ben Zeev and Pappa (2017) identify their military spending news shock in a SVAR model as the shock that has no contemporaneous impact on military spending while maximising the forecast error variance of military spending over a five-year horizon.

Defence fiscal multipliers are found to be state-dependent. The empirical literature usually finds evidence of fiscal multipliers being larger (i) in recessions (bad economic times), when the share of non-Ricardian consumers tends to increase and public spending can crowd in (rather than crowd out) private investment; (ii) when there is ample fiscal space or sound public finances (lower debt, deficit or lower interest rate-growth differential); (iii) for less open economies (less potential for spillovers outside the economy through imports); and (iv) for fixed-exchange rate systems (inactive monetary policy) (see Warmedinger et al. (2015) for a review). Similar results are found for defence spending multipliers in Sarasa-Flores (2025) (Chart A) and in Sheremirov and Spirovska (2022) (for fiscal multipliers of general government spending instrumented by military spending). The importance of state dependency (non-linearities) for good versus bad economic times is also emphasised in the meta-analysis of Gechert and Rannenberg (2018). Together with fiscal fundamentals, state dependency is an important aspect to be considered in the (linear) model-based simulations. This can be done by adequately varying the model parameters depending on the prevailing state.

Empirical studies of defence spending rarely investigate the effects on inflation directly. The few available studies for the United States tend to find a positive short-term effect. Ben Zeev and Pappa (2017) find military spending news to be inflationary, peaking after one year before returning to zero in year two. Looking at state-level effects on inflation of military spending, Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) find no cumulative effect after two years. More recently, Antonova et al. (2025) find that military spending news leads to higher manufacturing prices in the United States (while the impact on consumer price index inflation is not investigated). This effect was larger and more persistent in the post-Cold War period, when the US manufacturing sector shrank.

7 Conclusion

Against the backdrop of planned increases in defence spending in the euro area, a model-based assessment of government spending shocks suggests a positive effect on real GDP growth and a modest effect on HICP inflation, with significant uncertainty surrounding estimates. A persistent but gradual increase in military spending of 1% of GDP over three years is associated with a two-year GDP multiplier of 0.93 and a two-year impact on HICP inflation of 0.07 percentage points on average across different model types. There is substantial model heterogeneity, with output multipliers ranging from 0.42 to 1.13. Four years after the shock, the GDP multiplier remains at 0.93 on average, while HICP inflation increases by 0.2 percentage points on average across the models. Model-implied fiscal multipliers are generally aligned with the empirical evidence on the effects of military spending. We further identify key transmission channels that shape the economic effect of additional military spending: a higher share of investment produces larger spillovers, whereas the private sector anticipating higher taxes and interest rates plays a prominent role in reducing multipliers. Several aspects remain outside the scope of this analysis, in particular state dependency with respect to government indebtedness and bad versus good economic times, which is found to be relevant in the empirical literature. Finally, important aspects of military spending cannot be fully captured in this analysis. Examples include the composition of spending by single countries or sectoral supply and industry-network effects.

References

Adjemian, S., Bokan, N., Darracq Pariès, M., Müller, G. and Zimic, S. (2024), “ECB-(RE)BASE: Heterogeneity in expectation formation and macroeconomic dynamics”, Working Paper Series, No 2965, ECB, Frankfurt am Main.

Alptekin, A. and Levine, P. (2012), “Military expenditure and economic growth: A meta-analysis”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 28, No 4, pp. 636-650.

Angelini, E., Bokan, N., Christoffel, K., Ciccarelli, M. and Zimic, S. (2019), “Introducing ECB-BASE: The blueprint of the new ECB semi-structural model for the euro area”, Working Paper Series, No 2315, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, September.

Angelini, E., Bokan, N., Ciccarelli, M., Lalik, M. and Zimic, S. (forthcoming), “The ECB-Multi Country Model: A semi-structural model for forecasting and policy analysis for the largest euro area countries.” Working Paper Series, ECB, Frankfurt am Main.

Antolin-Diaz, J. and Surico, P. (2025), “The Long-Run Effects of Government Spending”, American Economic Review, Vol. 115, No 7, pp. 2376-2413.

Antonova, A., Luetticke, R. and Muller, G.J. (2025), “The Military Multiplier”, CESifo Working Paper, No 11882, CESifo GmbH, Munich, May.

Bańkowski, K. (2023), “Fiscal policy in the semi-structural model ECB-BASE”, Working Paper Series, No 2802, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, March.

Barro, R.J. and Redlick, C.J. (2011), “Macroeconomic Effects From Government Purchases and Taxes”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 126, No 1, pp. 51-102.

Becker, J. and Dunne, J.P. (2023), “Military Spending Composition and Economic Growth”, Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 34, No 3, pp. 259-271.

Ben Zeev, N. and Pappa, E. (2017), “Chronicle of a War Foretold: The Macroeconomic Effects of Anticipated Defence Spending Shocks”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 127, No 603, pp. 1568-1597.

Checherita-Westphal, C., Huber, C., Rodriguez-Vives, M. and Müller, G. (2025), “Fiscal aspects of European defence spending: implications for euro area macroeconomic projections and associated risks”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 5, ECB.

Coenen, G., Lozej, M. and Priftis, R. (2024), "Macroeconomic effects of carbon transition policies: An assessment based on the ECB’s New Area-Wide Model with a disaggregated energy sector," European Economic Review, Elsevier, Vol. 167.

Gechert, S. and Rannenberg, A. (2018), “Which fiscal multipliers are regime‐dependent? A meta‐regression analysis”, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 32, No 4, pp. 1160-1182.

Gomes, S., Jacquinot, P. and Pisani, M. (2012), “The EAGLE. A model for policy analysis of macroeconomic interdependence in the euro area”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 29, No 5, pp. 1686-1714.

Ilzetzki, E. (2025), “Guns and Growth: The Economic Consequences of Defense Buildups”, Kiel Report, No 2, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, February.

Kase, H. and Rigato, R. (2025), “Beyond averages: heterogeneous effects of monetary policy in a HANK model for the euro area”, Working Paper Series, No 3086, ECB, Frankfurt am Main.

Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2014), “Fiscal stimulus in a monetary union: Evidence from US regions”, American Economic Review, Vol. 104, No 3, pp. 753-792.

Olejnik, L.W. (2023), “Economic growth and military expenditure in the countries on NATO’s Eastern flank in 1999-2021”, Working Paper Series, No 2023/2, Eesti Pank.

Ramey, V.A. (2011), “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s all in the Timing”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 126, No 1, pp. 1-50.

Ramey, V.A. and Zubairy, S. (2018), “Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from US Historical Data”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 126, No 2, pp. 850-901.

Sarasa-Flores, D. (2025), “Buy Guns or Buy Roses?: EU Defence Spending Fiscal Multipliers”, Working Paper, No WP 25-06, BBVA Research, June.

Sheremirov, V. and Spirovska, S. (2022), “Fiscal multipliers in advanced and developing countries: Evidence from military spending”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 208, 104631.

Warmedinger, T., Checherita-Westphal, C. and Hernández de Cos, P. (2015), “Fiscal multipliers and beyond”, Occasional Paper Series, No 162, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, June.

Yesilyurt, F. and Yesilyurt, M.E. (2019), “Meta-analysis, military expenditures and growth”, Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 56, No 3, pp. 352-363.

  1. For previous studies investigating the implications of euro area governments’ defence spending plans for macroeconomic baseline projections and risk analysis, see Checherita-Westphal et al. (2025). That analysis focuses on new defence spending announced since February 2025, the associated risks, its country-specific compositional aspects and selected state dependencies. The simulations were conducted using the ECB’s projection models and assumed no monetary policy reaction.

  2. Most results in this article hold for increases in government spending of different magnitudes, as long as the effect on macroeconomic variables is scaled accordingly. NATO allies’ latest pledge is to increase core defence spending to 3.5% of GDP and to add further security-related spending of 1.5% of GDP such that total defence-related spending amounts to 5% of GDP. This annual spending is set to be achieved by 2035. The spending pattern in our analysis is therefore a stylised interpretation of the exact timing of the expenditure.

  3. The extension uses a calibrated non-linear NAWM-E to study spillovers within the monetary union in the spirit of EAGLE (Gomes et al., 2012) by allowing a dual-region disaggregation of the euro area into one core country (either Germany, Spain, France, Italy or the Netherlands) and a rest of the euro area aggregate.

  4. The rules according to which the central bank sets the interest rate in the models all follow the same principles of stabilising variations in inflation and output. The exact formulation and calibration of the rules are model-specific.

  5. It is assumed that there is no sovereign risk premium response to an increase in public debt. Therefore, the analysis in this article abstracts from the possible implications of a higher and increasing level of debt in individual countries. We also abstract from the banking sector transmitting the easing of balance sheet constraints to borrowing conditions and, more generally, set any financing spreads to the baseline level. Therefore, in these simulations, only expectations about future policy rates affect long-term interest rates (expectation hypothesis), which are then allowed to change external financing rates (via composite interest rates with constant spreads). The term premium is fixed to its baseline value throughout all simulations.

  6. In addition to the anticipation of future labour income, another positive effect on consumption stems from the accrual of additional financial wealth at higher interest rates. However, this effect is less important.

  7. These import shares are based on historical averages from Eurostat and reflect the entire set of sectoral components (both private and public). Because of this, they may not accurately represent spending focused specifically on defence in each final or intermediate consumption or investment sector.

  8. When public and private consumption are perceived as complements, higher public spending – such as defence expenditure that enhances security and stability – can crowd in private consumption, boosting the aggregate demand channel and reinforcing positive spillovers to the rest of the euro area.

  9. Arguably, the German fiscal surprise can be interpreted as reflecting a reassessment of heightened European security risks, with additional fiscal spending aimed at avoiding future demand losses that would occur without it rather than delivering a pure net gain. In this context, additional fiscal spending serves to preserve current consumption levels.

  10. The simulations assume that German government consumption good is produced with a higher share of imports – both from the rest of the euro area and the rest of the world – in proportion to its bilateral trade matrix. In particular, the import content of government consumption is doubled from 2% to 4%. Altering the composition of imports for Germany (e.g. by importing relatively more from the rest of the euro area than from the rest of the world) produces a stronger spillover to the rest of the euro area as a result of a strengthened trade channel. However, given the overall small import content of public spending and the small size of the fiscal impulse, the net difference to the euro area aggregate is negligible.

  11. Only three of the studies summarised in Chart A include estimates of the impact on private consumption. Ramey (2011) includes a specific discussion on the topic. By constructing a military spending news variable, she finds that both non-durable goods consumption and durable goods consumption decrease, while services consumption increases in response to military spending news. Ben Zeev and Pappa (2017) find a slight, but not statistically significant, decline in private consumption. Barro and Redlick (2011) find a negative impact only for durable goods consumption at the one-year horizon, which then fades.

  12. This finding holds on average and for expansionary periods. Conversely, military spending multipliers are found to be larger than general spending multipliers during recessionary periods.

  13. Using data for the United States over a period of 125 years (with a Bayesian Vector Autoregressive (BVAR) model with long lags), Antolin-Diaz and Surico (2025) find that military spending has large and persistent effects on output because it shifts the composition of public spending towards R&D. This boosts innovation and private investment in the medium term and increases productivity and GDP at longer horizons. By contrast, the paper also finds that public investment effects are shorter-lived and public consumption has a modest impact at most horizons